c1 3008204 250422071531

Global South Pays the Price as Trump’s Tariffs Drive a Global Trade War

World Culture

A sweeping set of tariff measures announced by the United States under President Donald Trump has unleashed a fresh wave of global economic turmoil. Markets around the world have wobbled as investors weigh the potential for higher consumer prices, disrupted supply chains, and a protracted confrontation with China. In many low- and middle-income economies that depend heavily on exporting to the United States, the mood has shifted from cautious optimism to outright anxiety about growth prospects, debt service, and social stability. As policymakers grapple with uncertainty, the very architecture of global trade and finance faces renewed stress, with the developing world positioned to bear the heaviest load even as the United States claims strategic leverage. This article explores the policy maneuvers, the mechanics of the tariff regime, the likely channels of impact, and the broader economic, financial, and geopolitical consequences that are unfolding in real time.

The tariff package: scope, exemptions, and immediate market effects

The administration introduced a broad package of tariffs that remains in effect despite a superficially reassuring pause. A universal 10% tariff on all US imports continues to apply, creating a broad-based tax on consumption that will reverberate through prices for goods ranging from apparel to electronics. In addition, sector-specific tariffs of 25% are imposed on steel and aluminum, as well as on automobiles and auto parts, expanding the sanction’s reach into several major downstream industries. Notably, there are exemptions designed to shield certain consumer electronics such as smartphones, computers, and related devices, which introduces a selective relief that complicates the overall price dynamics for end users and businesses. Yet, even with these exemptions, the tariff framework is generally expected to tighten domestic and international supply chains by altering relative costs and incentives across sectors.

The Trump administration has also retained a punitive stance toward China, elevating the tariff on Chinese imports to 145% after previously signalling an openness to negotiation and a temporary pause on some reciprocal measures. The 145% rate is widely viewed as a symbolic, retaliatory signal in response to China’s own tariff increases, especially given that the prior 104% rate had already rendered a substantial share of Chinese goods less competitive in the US market. In practice, the combination of a 145% tariff on Chinese goods and 10% universal tariffs, with additional sectoral duties, constitutes a broad-based strategy aimed at constraining the flow of foreign goods into the United States and pressuring other economies to realign their production and sourcing arrangements. The administration has described the policy as a recalibration intended to protect American workers and critical domestic industries, but the design also raises questions about the effectiveness and unintended consequences of such measures.

Amid these tariff moves, policymakers have signalled potential new duties on other strategic inputs, including pharmaceuticals, semiconductors, copper, and lumber. There are also ongoing considerations about further carve-outs or temporary exemptions for certain technologies and consumer devices, which introduces a dynamic, ever-shifting landscape for importers, manufacturers, and retailers. Taken together, the tariff regime is expected to reduce the availability of imported goods, push up prices for US consumers, and impose significant costs on countries that export to the United States. The combination of a universal tariff base, sector-specific levies, and targeted exemptions creates a complex matrix that complicates pricing, planning, and risk management for firms engaged in international trade.

Finally, the overall architecture of the tariff regime—comprising a general tariff floor, industry-specific charges, and sectoral exemptions—means that the final impact will not be uniform across sectors or geographies. The way these measures interact with existing trade agreements, tariff schedules, and the evolving negotiation posture will shape which countries face the steepest costs and how quickly supply chains adapt. For companies with heavy exposure to imported inputs or to US consumer demand, the near-term effect will likely be higher input costs, accelerated inventory reconfigurations, and a recalibration of offshore sourcing strategies to mitigate exposure. In short, the tariff package is designed to reshape cost structures, production decisions, and market dynamics across a broad spectrum of industries, while also signaling the administration’s willingness to use tariffs as a tool of strategic diplomacy and economic leverage.

Negotiations, hardball tactics, and the uncertainty premium

A central feature of the tariff episode is the uncertainty surrounding the final scope and duration of tariffs as negotiations unfold. Although there was a brief moment of market calm following the pause on many reciprocal tariffs, the respite proved superficial. The administration’s negotiating posture has been described as unusually aggressive, with public statements that underscore a willingness to apply pressure and to use rhetoric aimed at shaping the terms of future agreements. The volatile, sometimes theatrical, nature of policy announcements adds a premium of risk that market participants must price into asset valuations, corporate plans, and sovereign risk assessments. This environment makes it difficult for firms to plan capital expenditure, allocate resources, or forecast earnings with a high degree of confidence.

The rhetoric surrounding tariff policy has also complicated diplomatic engagement with a range of trading partners. The president’s public remarks have at times criticized foreign leaders in blunt terms, conveying a perception that key partners must concede or concede quickly to the administration’s terms. This approach reinforces a broader strategic calculus: that the final shape of tariffs is contingent on win‑lose negotiations in which the United States seeks to extract concessions, safeguard strategic industries, and recalibrate the balance of trade. As a result, the ultimate scope of the tariffs—and whether they will be broadened, rolled back, or repackaged—remains uncertain. For policymakers and market participants alike, the absence of a clear, credible path to resolution risks entrenching protective postures and prolonging volatility across the global economy.

The immediate implication for investors and businesses is a continued need to stress-test supply chains, hedging strategies, and balance sheets against a backdrop of shifting policy signals. Companies with diversified sourcing, regional footprints, or agile procurement capabilities may be better positioned to weather abrupt shifts, whereas those with heavy reliance on single-country supply chains—or on inputs from politically sensitive regions—face heightened exposure to tariff-induced cost shocks and potential disruption. The policy framework’s ambiguity also impedes the ability of researchers and risk managers to apply conventional models with confidence, forcing reliance on scenario analysis, stress testing, and contingency planning. In this sense, the uncertainty premium associated with tariff negotiations translates into higher discount rates, greater risk premia, and a more cautious environment for long-horizon investments.

Finally, the broader geopolitical context matters. The tariff strategy is part of a larger contest over economic influence, technology leadership, and global governance. As the United States asserts its preferences and recalibrates its economic alliances, other major economies—most notably China—are pressed to respond not only on price and volume, but also on issues of technology access, supply chain resilience, and strategic autonomy. In such a milieu, the final configuration of tariffs will likely reflect a bargaining landscape in which both sides test limits, reveal red lines, and attempt to shape long-run strategic outcomes. The net effect is a world that must operate under greater policy ambiguity, with capital markets, firms, and workers adjusting incrementally as negotiations progress and outcomes remain unclear.

The Sino-American dynamic: escalation, timing, and the long game

A critical axis of the tariff episode is the ongoing Sino-American confrontation, which has evolved into a persistent, high-stakes strategic contest. The latest move—the substantial hike on Chinese imports to 145%—appears, on the surface, to be a retaliatory signal rather than a purely economic calculation. It follows China’s own tariff increases and is widely understood as an attempt to deter further escalation by signaling resolve, while giving space for negotiations to proceed. Yet, in practical terms the 145% levy reinforces a trajectory in which the United States signals a willingness to disrupt normal trade patterns in order to extract concessions that it views as essential to preserving domestic economic and security interests. The essential takeaway is that the Sino-American trade relationship has entered a phase in which the boundary between negotiation and punishment becomes increasingly porous, creating a climate of heightened risk for both economies and the global trading system.

In effect, the administration’s decision to press the 145% rate against Chinese imports solidifies a dynamic in which the Sino-American trade war is set to persist. The prior 104% rate had already rendered a substantial portion of Chinese goods economically nonviable within the United States, and the newer rate serves to intensify the economic frictions without yet delivering a comprehensive resolution. The result is a situation in which both sides are compelled to rethink supply chains, sourcing strategies, and the structure of their bilateral trade—often with the aim of reducing dependence on the other side. The implications for US consumers and for domestic producers that depend on Chinese inputs are particularly consequential. Companies may accelerate diversification away from Chinese sourcing, reshaping regional production hubs and intensifying efforts to secure alternative suppliers.

For governments that hinge on the United States market or on Chinese technology and components, the policy environment now demands rapid adaptation. The prospect of sustained disruption pushes decision-makers to examine diversified sourcing options, onshoring or nearshoring opportunities, and the cultivation of strategic stockpiles for critical inputs. The broader impact on global supply chains is a slowdown and rerouting of trade flows that can ripple through manufacturing calendars, inventory cycles, and investment plans. In this context, the Sino-American standoff is not simply a bilateral issue but a global phenomenon that influences the terms of trade, the geography of manufacturing, and the architecture of global finance.

Global supply chains, prices, and the burden on households

The consequences for US households and domestic producers that rely on Chinese inputs are likely to be far-reaching. The administration’s stance toward goods manufactured in Chinese facilities—especially those routed through third countries—reflects an overarching suspicion of the integrity and reliability of supply networks that have grown increasingly complex and interdependent over decades. Governments faced with this reality are pressing to identify alternative sourcing strategies and production footprints, a process that can be protracted and costly. Even where exemptions exist for certain consumer devices, the broader effect is to tighten the availability of imported goods and to push up prices for a wide range of products.

From a macroeconomic perspective, the tariffs act as a form of invisible tax that reduces consumer purchasing power and shifts consumption toward domestically produced substitutes or higher-cost alternatives. The combination of universal tariff coverage and sector-specific duties is likely to compress real incomes, especially for lower- and middle-income households that already devote a large share of their budgets to essential goods. The resulting price pressures may dampen consumer demand, slow job growth in dependent sectors, and weigh on retail activity. Firms that rely on imported content, particularly in electronics, automotive, and machinery industries, face higher input costs, potential margin compression, and a need to pass some costs to customers to preserve profitability. This chain reaction has broad implications for inflation trajectories, monetary policy, and the stance of fiscal support in response to the tariff shocks.

The disruptions to supply chains extend beyond the United States and affect partner economies country by country. When the cost of inputs rises, producers in exporting nations react with a mix of price adjustments, capacity reallocation, and, in some cases, reduced output. Because many developing economies compete for access to the US market, a significant reconfiguration of regional supply networks can have outsized effects on employment and industrial clusters. The immediate risk is a period of elevated volatility as firms experiment with alternate suppliers and adjust to new cost structures, while producers in importing countries must absorb higher costs or pass them through to consumers. Over time, these shifts can contribute to changes in comparative advantage, alter trade patterns, and shape the evolution of global production networks.

At the same time, there are potential positive channels for some segments of the economy. In the United States, some sectors may benefit from a reduced dependence on foreign inputs or from policy-driven investments in domestic capacity and automation. Countries that manage to attract manufacturing activity as companies diversify their supply chains may see a boost in jobs and a rebalancing of regional economic activity. Yet the overall effect, especially for low- and middle-income economies that rely on export-led growth models, is likely to be adverse in the near term, as the global demand environment becomes more uncertain and credit conditions tighten.

Uncertainty around policy direction also weighs on investment decisions. Firms often maintain a degree of hedging to manage exposure to tariff-induced price volatility and exchange-rate risk. The erratic decision-making pattern associated with tariff announcements exacerbates this challenge: capital projects may be postponed, expansions delayed, and financing costs may rise as risk premia increase. The net effect is a slowdown in investment and a drag on productivity growth, which, when compounded across the economy, can depress potential output and slow improvement in living standards for households.

For policymakers, the trade-off is stark. They must balance the political and strategic objectives of tariffs with their consequences for consumer welfare, business investment, and macroeconomic stability. The ability to calibrate policy to minimize reach without sacrificing strategic goals will likely determine the durability of the policy framework and the resilience of the economy under stress. The practical reality is that tariffs create a new layer of friction in an already complex global economy, requiring firms and governments to navigate a landscape in which costs, availability, and timing are all in flux.

Financial markets under pressure: uncertainty, risk, and the credibility of Treasuries

The tariff episode has prompted a notable recalibration in global financial markets. The initial market response—volatility, flight-to-safety tendencies, and a reassessment of risk premia—reflects investors’ concern about the durability of US leadership in the face of escalating trade barriers. A broader concern is the potential for a sustained deceleration in US growth, which would affect corporate earnings, consumer demand, and the trajectory of monetary policy. The nervousness extends beyond equities into fixed income markets, where shifts in expectations about inflation, dollar strength, and the risk of a policy misstep feed into price movements across a wide range of assets.

An early warning signal of the shifting environment is the observed fall in demand for US Treasury bills, a cornerstone of global financial safety. Treasuries have long been considered a benchmark asset for price discovery and liquidity; a decline in demand signals a reassessment of the stability and credibility of the United States’ financial leadership. Simultaneously, the pressure on stocks, bonds, and the U.S. dollar—a trio that has underpinned the global funding and currency exchange apparatus—points to growing doubts about the ability of US Treasuries to maintain their traditional anchor role in asset pricing. This complex dynamic raises concerns about the possibility of an outright de-risking cycle across emerging markets, as investors reassess the role of US debt in diversified portfolios.

For emerging and developing economies, the market response has been pronounced and instructive. Sovereign dollar-denominated debt across these economies has experienced meaningful price moves, with spreads widening and yields rising as investors demand higher compensation for increased risk. Data in the months surrounding the tariff announcements show a broad-based deterioration in the perceived creditworthiness of several debt-stressed economies. Among the notable cases are the Maldives, Sri Lanka, Gabon, and Zambia, where sovereign debt values declined by more than 10% within a short window. This tightening of financial conditions is not merely a temporary disruption; it signals tighter financing conditions that can feed back into the real economy through higher borrowing costs, delayed government projects, and reduced public investment.

The volatility in sovereign debt markets also underscores the vulnerability of developing economies to shifts in global risk appetite. When global financial conditions tighten, these countries often experience capital outflows, currency depreciation, and higher servicing costs for existing debt denominated in foreign currency. The net effect is a cycle in which currency depreciation exacerbates debt burdens, domestic inflationary pressures rise, and fiscal deficits widen. Such dynamics can force policymakers to pursue austerity measures, tighten spending, or seek external financial support under often stringent conditions that may further constrain growth. The balance of risks is difficult: while a softer dollar and more favorable credit conditions could alleviate some pressure, the tariff-related uncertainty makes the outlook inherently fragile.

Beyond the immediate market mechanics, the tariff policy’s impact on financial globalization is a matter of concern for stakeholders worldwide. The harmonized functioning of cross-border finance—reliant on the predictability of policy, trust in institutions, and confidence in long-run exchange-rate stability—faces a test as risk perceptions shift. If the United States is perceived as pursuing a more volatile, coercive, or fragmented economic stance, capital may seek safer or more predictable jurisdictions, and global liquidity could reallocate toward markets deemed safer or more structurally resilient. This reallocation has broad implications for currency markets, interest-rate dynamics, and the global supply of capital for development and investment projects.

The development challenge: debt, depreciation, and the broader vulnerability of emerging economies

Developing economies have long contended with a cycle of currency depreciation, elevated borrowing costs, fiscal tightening, and domestic market instability. The current tariff shock intensifies these long-standing vulnerabilities by threatening export demand, disrupting production lines, and raising the cost of imports for essential inputs. The combination of higher external financing costs and reduced external demand can rapidly erode macroeconomic stability, challenge debt sustainability, and complicate policy responses. The developing world’s exposure to trade policy risk is not merely about the price of goods; it is about the capacity of governments to fund development programs, maintain social protection, and invest in infrastructure that supports long-run growth.

This environment tends to reverberate through sovereign debt markets, public finances, and private sector investment. As yields on sovereign debt rise and prices fall, borrowing costs for development projects can become a bottleneck, delaying critical capital expenditure on health, education, and productivity-enhancing infrastructure. The resulting slowdown in public investment compounds private-sector hesitancy, as higher financing costs and greater policy uncertainty dampen entrepreneurial risk-taking and hinder job creation. In the developing world, these effects are particularly pronounced because growth models often rely on external financing, export-led demand, and capital inflows to sustain expansion.

The lessons for policymakers in these economies become clearer in this context. First, globalized trade and financial globalization are being tested by a policy regime that prioritizes strategic leverage over shared prosperity. Second, the need to diversify trade relationships and to bolster internal resilience becomes more urgent. Third, fiscal discipline and credible debt management emerge as crucial tools to navigate periods of volatility without compromising essential public investments. The combination of supply-chain diversification, domestic capacity building, and prudent fiscal and monetary governance can help mitigate the worst effects of tariff-induced disruptions. However, any such strategy requires time, resources, and structural reforms that may be painful in the short term but could yield more stable, self-reliant growth in the longer horizon.

Uncertainty, investment, and long-run growth: macroeconomic consequences

A central concern is how rising policy uncertainty translates into slower investment and lower long-run growth. Uncertainty, by nature, deters firms from committing capital to new projects and expansions, as the cost-benefit calculus becomes clouded by unpredictable policy directions. The erratic nature of decision-making, sudden reversals, and on-again, off-again announcements associated with tariff policy amplifies this aversion to risk, leading to delays in plant-building, research and development, and hiring. The immediate macroeconomic consequence is a softer trajectory for gross investment and a potential drag on productivity growth as firms postpone capital deepening and technological upgrading.

Additionally, the broader concern is whether this mode of policy signaling will become a recurring feature of the global economy. If other major economies perceive that the United States is willing to use tariffs as a primary instrument of economic policy—coupled with abrupt policy reversals and a high degree of unpredictability—they may adjust their own policy stances in ways that further fragment global trade and investment. The risk is the emergence of a more fragmented international order in which regional blocs and alliance networks pursue insulated growth strategies rather than integrated, rules-based trade. This could erode the gains of global value chains that organizations and firms have built over decades, leading to a more multipolar, less predictable economic landscape.

From a productivity perspective, sustained uncertainty can degrade business confidence, slow the pace of innovation, and shift investment toward safer, more easily reversible projects. In manufacturing and services alike, companies may prioritize incremental improvements over transformative investments, thereby postponing breakthroughs that drive long-run efficiency gains. The cumulative effect on potential output would be a slower rate of trend growth, with knock-on implications for living standards, wage growth, and employment opportunities. The broader social and political consequences—such as greater income inequality, social tension, and pressure on social safety nets—may follow as the economy adjusts to a new, less tranquil equilibrium.

Policy responses to this uncertainty will matter a great deal. Monetary authorities may face a delicate balancing act between supporting growth and controlling inflation if tariff shocks feed into consumer prices. Fiscal authorities may be drawn into countercyclical measures, targeted relief, or selective subsidies to cushion vulnerable households and sectors while maintaining incentives for investment. The design of these interventions—timing, scale, and targeting—will influence how effectively economies can absorb tariff-related shocks and maintain a trajectory of inclusive growth. The interplay between monetary policy, fiscal policy, and trade policy thus becomes a central arena in which the path toward stability will be decided.

The geopolitical and strategic dimensions: long-term implications for global order

Beyond immediate economic effects, the tariff episode carries significant geopolitical implications. The United States’ stated aim of dismantling aspects of the existing global economic order reflects a broader strategy to recalibrate international economic rules in a way that places US interests at the center. In this framing, allies and competitors alike are prompted to reassess their participation in a system that they perceive as increasingly skewed or coercive. The developing world, in particular, is forced to confront the reality that the current system may no longer offer the predictable, long-horizon financing and market access that many economies require to sustain development trajectories. In this sense, a potential outcome is a realignment of economic loyalties and a rethinking of how to engage with a trading system built on liberal principles but now perceived as subject to abrupt shifts in policy direction.

China’s strategy in this environment appears designed to endure and adapt over the long run. Observers anticipate a sustained challenge to the traditional Western-led order, with Beijing pursuing a strategy that emphasizes resilience, diversification of supply chains, and greater financial and political influence in other regions. The risk is that both sides settle into a protracted contest in which economic diplomacy, technology access, and strategic investments become the main instruments of influence. The possibility of a broader financial crisis or even a multi-domain confrontation—spanning economic, technological, and possibly geopolitical fronts—cannot be ruled out if miscalculations accumulate and trust erodes further.

Within this evolving landscape, the fall in demand for US Treasuries—once considered among the safest assets in the world—serves as a loud warning signal. The market’s reassessment of the United States’ leadership and its ability to sustain a dominant role in global finance raises questions about the durability of the current reserve-currency regime and the broader stability of global asset pricing benchmarks. If Treasuries lose their appeal as a universal asset class, the ripple effects could touch every corner of global markets, restructuring portfolios, altering risk premia, and complicating the financing of development and public investment programs around the world.

In parallel, the coordination of monetary and fiscal responses will be tested. Advanced economies may find it easier to deploy policy tools to stabilize markets, while developing economies will need to navigate a more fragile external environment with limited room for policy manoeuvre. This imbalance could intensify the disparities between nations, amplifying the need for international cooperation, credible governance, and reforms that can underpin more resilient financial architecture. The idea of a more liquid, stable, and inclusive global economy hinges on credible institutions, transparent policy signaling, and mechanisms that can dampen the kind of sudden shifts that tariffs tend to introduce.

The human and social costs: employment, living standards, and resilience

Tariffs of the scale contemplated and implemented carry direct and indirect consequences for employment and living standards. In export-oriented sectors and in the supply chains that connect them, production disruptions and higher input costs can translate into job losses or slower job creation. In some regions, factory closures or plant relocations could intensify local unemployment and place additional pressure on social safety nets. The worry extends to consumer households that see prices rise for everyday goods. If inflation accelerates due to tariff-driven costs, real incomes can stagnate or decline, particularly for low- and middle-income households that spend a larger share of their budgets on essential items.

The social costs may also manifest in heightened political and social tensions, as communities facing job displacement or rising prices demand policy action. Governments might respond with targeted subsidies, retraining programs, or support for small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) to cushion the impact of tariff shocks. However, the efficacy of such measures depends on design, implementation speed, and fiscal space. The risk is that policy responses could be too little, too late, or misdirected, leaving vulnerable populations exposed to a protracted period of adjustment with limited relief.

Beyond national borders, the global impact on workers and families in trading partner countries can be substantial. If demand for their exports weakens due to tariff protectionism in the United States, those economies may experience a deterioration in employment prospects, rising poverty rates, and slower improvements in human development indicators. The interconnected nature of modern labor markets means that the consequences of tariff policy reverberate far beyond the borders of the United States, affecting global welfare and contributing to complexities in migration patterns, remittances, and regional development prospects.

The path forward: finding credible alternatives and stabilizing the system

The policy path ahead hinges on whether there can be a credible, durable alternative to the current approach that can reconcile strategic objectives with the need for global economic stability. For developing economies, the practical lessons point toward diversifying export markets, strengthening domestic capabilities, and promoting resilient supply chains that can weather policy shocks. To a degree, this means investing in diversification of partner economies, increasing the self-reliance of critical sectors, and pursuing domestic reforms that enhance productivity and competitiveness. It also means securing access to capital with more favorable terms and building credible institutions that reassure international lenders about debt sustainability and macroeconomic discipline.

From the perspective of the United States, achieving a sustainable equilibrium will require balancing political objectives with economic practicality. This includes carefully calibrating tariffs to minimize unintended inflationary effects and supply-chain disruptions, while negotiating in good faith to address core concerns about unfair trade practices, market access, and national security considerations. The goal would be to preserve the best features of the liberal trading system—predictability, rule-based dispute resolution, and mutual gains—while implementing reforms that respond to legitimate domestic concerns. That balance is difficult but essential if the global economy is to avoid a protracted period of volatility and decoupling that could undermine growth and development prospects for years to come.

A broader policy framework for the international community might emphasize cooperation on supply-chain resilience, mutual investment promotion, and rules-based mechanisms that can address targeted concerns without triggering a global protectionist downturn. Strengthened dialogue among major economies, an emphasis on transparent policy signaling, and the development of joint risk-management tools could help reduce the volatility that tariffs tend to generate. In addition, reform of international financial architecture to improve liquidity, crisis-prevention, and debt sustainability for developing economies could make the global system more robust in the face of policy shocks. The objective would be to build an international environment in which strategic aims and economic welfare can be pursued in a complementary fashion, rather than in opposition to one another.

The road to a credible alternative arrangement will require time, coordination, and sustained political will across countries with divergent interests. It will also demand a rethinking of how global prosperity is organized—moving away from unilateral coercion toward collaborative strategies that align incentives, stabilize markets, and protect the most vulnerable segments of the global population. The outcome may involve reformative steps toward a more inclusive and resilient framework for trade, finance, and development—one that recognizes the legitimate priorities of workers and households while preserving the dynamics of global commerce that have historically supported growth and poverty reduction.

Conclusion

The tariff policy now shaping the global economic landscape is a defining moment for the world economy. It tests the resilience of supply chains, the credibility of financial benchmarks, and the willingness of nations to pursue a shared path toward stable growth. The immediate effects—higher prices for imported goods, disrupted production schedules, and elevated uncertainty—fall hardest on those least able to absorb shocks. Yet the longer-term implications extend beyond inflation dynamics and quarterly earnings: they touch on the nature of global economic governance, the behavior of investors, and the future of development in the world’s most vulnerable economies.

If the United States remains steadfast in its approach without a credible mechanism for resolution, the result could be a slower, less integrated, and more volatile global economy. The developing world, already accustomed to cycles of volatility, is likely to bear the most substantial burden, facing higher debt costs, weaker export demand, and the risk of social and political strain as households absorb the consequences. Conversely, if policymakers can craft a pathway that preserves strategic objectives while restoring predictability and fairness in international trade, a more stable and inclusive trajectory might emerge—one that protects vulnerable communities, sustains investment, and preserves the gains of globalisation while addressing legitimate concerns about unfair practices and national security.

In this evolving scenario, the key to stability lies in credible policy design, disciplined risk management, and a renewed commitment to international collaboration. The path forward will require a careful balance between defending national interests and maintaining the open, rules-based framework that has historically underpinned economic growth and poverty reduction. Only through thoughtful negotiation, transparent decision-making, and robust international cooperation can the international community hope to minimize the worst outcomes of tariff confrontation and to chart a course toward a more resilient global economy.